Economic Research Forum (ERF)

Inflation targeting and exchange rate flexibility in Egypt

1309
The degree of exchange rate flexibility within an inflation targeting framework matters in emerging economies. This column reports research that quantifies the impact of different approaches to the conduct of monetary policy on inflation and output variability in Egypt.

In a nutshell

Analysis of monetary policy in Egypt indicates that a fixed exchange rate regime generates the highest output and inflation variability, in addition to the worst loss function for the economy.

As the exchange rate is allowed more flexibility, the variability of output and inflation declines.

Monetary policy has many more opportunities to correct its mistakes when targeting inflation rather than the exchange rate.

Inflation targeting is one of the operational frameworks for monetary policy aimed at attaining price stability. In contrast to alternative strategies, notably money or exchange rate targeting, which seek to achieve low and stable inflation through targeting intermediate variables – for example, the growth rate of money aggregates or the level of the exchange rate against an ‘anchor’ currency – inflation targeting focuses directly on inflation.

Economic research has identified a relatively long list of requirements for countries trying to operate a successful inflation targeting framework. Key among them is the need for increased exchange rate flexibility to eliminate confusion surrounding the central bank’s nominal anchor.

But in many cases, particularly in emerging markets, inflation targeting is pursued without completely fulfilling the exchange rate requirements. This is done on the grounds that there is a high pass-through from exchange rate fluctuations to inflation in these countries. Hence, it is argued, if the overriding concern is to reduce inflation variability and, in turn, output variability, there will be a tendency to maintain some exchange rate rule.

Although a functioning exchange rate transmission channel may add to the effectiveness of monetary policy under inflation targeting, actively manipulating the exchange rate along with inflation is likely to worsen the performance of monetary policy. But this does not imply that central banks should not pay attention to the exchange rate.

While inflation targeting may be a framework that is typically free from formal exchange rate commitments, it is nonetheless not free from exchange rate considerations. The apparent reluctance of policy-makers to take a completely hands-off approach to the exchange rate may reflect neither an irrational fear nor an unconditional distaste for floating per se.

There are many good reasons for any open economy to be concerned about certain types or magnitudes of exchange rate movements, such as the high degree of exchange rate pass-through, effects on the external sector, financial stability and market functioning.

Against this background, research and country experience in this area have focused on introducing an exchange rate term into the central bank’s reaction function under an inflation targeting regime.

My work builds on this research by presenting a small open economy structural gap model with forward-looking expectations and with an endogenous monetary policy response for the case of Egypt (Al-Mashat, 2011). The study examines the consequences of various approaches to the conduct of monetary policy by presenting the variability of inflation and output in the light of alternative degrees of exchange rate intervention under an inflation targeting regime for Egypt.

As is evident in Figures 1 and 2, the closer the system is to a fixed exchange rate regime, the higher are the inflation variability and output variability. The variability starts to decline as the exchange rate starts to become more flexible. Unsurprisingly, this is consistent with a situation where the central bank adopts a monetary policy reaction function that is closer to an inflation targeting regime.

In pegged regimes, central banks are punished for their mistakes by financial markets, which act swiftly and with a force that is hard to counteract. On the other hand, mistakes in inflation targeting regimes are punished by consumers (and the public in general) through their expectations – and these evolve only gradually. In practice, then, monetary policy has many more opportunities to correct its mistakes when targeting inflation rather than the exchange rate.

The higher volatility of the variables under a fixed exchange rate regime does not come from the absence of the direct exchange rate to inflation channel of transmission. It is the demand side that stabilises the economy.

In driving demand, however, the real exchange rate does not help to stabilise the shock when the nominal exchange rate is fixed as much as when the exchange rate is flexible. Hence, nominal (and real) interest rates have to move more to compensate for this.

In other words, the conduct of monetary policy targeting inflation while maintaining a fixed exchange rate regime has to count on a larger volatility of its main macroeconomic variables, particularly output.

In addition to examining inflation and output variability, it is important to evaluate the ‘loss function’ under the various exchange rate flexibility and inflation targeting scenarios. The loss function summarises the trade-off between inflation and output by providing a combination of inflation and output variability rather than emphasising the importance of one variable over the other.

Previous results are confirmed in Figure 3, where the fixed exchange rate regime provides the highest loss in terms of inflation and output variability put together.

To sum up, the results reveal that a fixed exchange rate regime generates the highest output and inflation variability, in addition to the worst loss function for the economy. As the exchange rate is allowed more flexibility, the variability of output and inflation declines.

Further reading

Al-Mashat, Rania (2011) ‘Assessing Inflation and Output Variability using a New Keynesian Model: An Application to Egypt’, in Money in the Middle East and North Africa: Monetary Policy Frameworks and Strategies edited by David Cobham and Ghassan Dibeh, Routledge.

Al-Mashat, Rania (2007) ‘Monetary Policy in Egypt: A Retrospective and Preparedness for Inflation Targeting’, Egyptian Center for Economic Studies Working Paper No. 134.

Al-Mashat, Rania, and Andreas Billmeier (2008) ‘The Monetary Transmission Mechanism in Egypt’, Review of Middle East Economics and Finance 4(3).

Benes, Jaromir, and David Varva (2004) ‘Exchange Rate Pegs and Inflation Targeting: Modeling the Exchange Rate in Reduced Form New Keynesian models’, mimeo, Czech National Bank.

Berg, Andrew, Philippe Karam and Douglas Laxton (2006) ‘Practical Model-based Monetary Policy Analysis – A How-to Guide’, International Monetary Fund Working Paper No. 06/81.

 

 

Most read

Labour market effects of robots: evidence from Turkey

Evidence from developed countries on the impact of automation on labour markets suggests that there can be negative effects on manufacturing jobs, but also mechanisms for workers to move into the services sector. But this narrative may not apply in developing economies. This column reports new evidence from Turkey on the effects of robots on labour displacement and job reallocation.

Global value chains and domestic innovation: evidence from MENA firms

Global interlinkages play a significant role in enhancing innovation by firms in developing countries. In particular, as this column explains, participation in global value chains fosters a variety of innovation activities. Since some countries in the Middle East and North Africa display a downward trend on measures of global innovation, facilitating the GVC participation of firms in the region is a prospective channel for stimulating underperforming innovation.

Food insecurity in Tunisia during and after the Covid-19 pandemic

Labour market instability, rising unemployment rates and soaring food prices due to Covid-19 are among the reasons for severe food insecurity across the world. This grim picture is evident in Tunisia, where the government continues to provide financial and food aid to vulnerable households after the pandemic. But as this column explains, the inadequacy of some public policies is another important factors causing food insecurity.

Sustaining entrepreneurship: lessons from Iran

Does entrepreneurial activity naturally return to long-term average levels after big economic disturbances? This column presents new evidence from Iran on trends in entrepreneurship among various categories of firm size, sector and location – and suggests policies that could be effective in promoting entrepreneurial activities.

Manufacturing firms in Egypt: trade participation and outcomes for workers

International trade can play a large and positive role in boosting economic growth, reducing poverty and making progress towards gender equality. These effects result in part from the extent to which trade is associated with favourable labour market outcomes. This column presents evidence of the effects of Egyptian manufacturing firms’ participation in exporting and importing on their workers’ productivity and average wages, and on women’s employment share.

Intimate partner violence: the impact on women’s empowerment in Egypt

Although intimate partner violence is a well-documented and widely recognised problem, empirical research on its prevalence and impact is scarce in developing countries, including those in the Middle East and North Africa. This column reports evidence from a study of intra-household disparities in Egypt, taking account of attitudes toward gender roles, women’s ownership of assets, and the domestic violence that wives may experience from their husbands.

Do capital inflows cause industrialisation or de-industrialisation?

There is a clear appeal for emerging and developing economies, including those in MENA, to finance investment in manufacturing industry at home with capital inflows from overseas. But as the evidence reported in this column indicates, this is a potentially risky strategy: rather than promoting industrialisation, capital flows can actually lead to lower manufacturing value added and/or a reallocation of resources towards industries with lower technology intensity.

Financial constraints on small firms’ growth: pandemic lessons from Iran

How does access to finance affect the growth of small businesses? This column presents new evidence from Iran before and during the Covid-19 pandemic – and lessons learned by micro, small and medium-sized enterprises.

The economics of Israeli war aims and strategies

Israel’s response to last October’s Hamas attack has led to widespread death and destruction. This column outlines the impact thus far, including the effects on food scarcity, migration and the Palestinian economy in both Gaza and the West Bank.