Economic Research Forum (ERF)

Exchange rate undervaluation: the impact on participation in world trade

866
Can currency undervaluation influence participation in world trade through global value chains (GVC)? This column reports new evidence on the positive impact of an undervalued real exchange rate on the involvement of a country’s firms in GVCs. Undervaluation acts as an economy-wide industrial policy, supporting the competitiveness of national exports in foreign markets vis-à-vis those of other countries.

In a nutshell

A country that has an undervalued currency on global foreign exchange markets is likely to benefit from a positive impact on its firms’ participation in global value chains; this applies to both backward and forward linkages within GVCs.

Exchange rate undervaluation acts as a compensatory factor for countries with weak institutions; the impact of this undervaluation becomes more pronounced as the level of digitisation in the economy increases.

Undervaluation is both feasible and effective as strategy in the short term – perhaps even several years – but it is not a substitute for building robust institutions in the longer run; even in the short term, its effectiveness is contingent on a higher level of digital transformation.

Global value chains (GVC) are increasingly dominating trade relations. Participation in GVCs sustains both high economic growth and the structural transformation of the economy. This is because participating countries can enter niches along the chain without having to produce the whole product through vertical specialisation.

The Middle East and North Africa as a region is still underperforming in GVC participation compared with other emerging and developing regions. Based on our research, we argue that part of the explanation might lie in currency markets since undervaluation of the real exchange rate (RER) is among a set of determinants that matter for GVC participation. This applies to both backward linkages (value added in exports whose outputs are produced by foreign industries) and forward linkages (domestic value added that is embodied in the exports of other countries).

In general, RER undervaluation acts as an economy-wide industrial policy, supporting the competitiveness of a country’s exports vis-à-vis other countries’ exports in foreign markets.

Rodrik (2008) argues that empirical findings on the prominence of RER reflect a deeper causal effect. According to his analysis, to the extent that tradable economic activities are more ‘complex’ and therefore entail more transaction-intensive activities, they tend to be more affected by the cost associated with weak institutions. Hence, the economy-wide subsidy provided by RER undervaluation should at least partially reduce this cost.

Evidence of the robust association between mild undervaluation and fast export-oriented growth could be explained by the fact that, in general, tradables tend to be more dynamic than non-tradables. The equally robust evidence on the negative effect of RER overvaluation could be explained as well. Yet in a world characterised by the increasing role of GVCs since the 1990s and cross-border fragmentation of production, the evidence from previous research may become less intuitive.

Evidence on the role of RER undervaluation typically hinges on the assumption that countries export only final goods that do not require imported intermediate inputs. Such a simplifying assumption does not reflect the complex reality of trade relations, especially GVC trade, where products become multi-country products as intermediate inputs are imported, transformed and then re-exported. Thus, GVC-related trade is expected to respond differently to exchange rate undervaluation compared with traditional trade in single-country goods.

We provide evidence in support of this proposition using a sample of 143 countries over the period 1995-2018 drawn from the UNCTAD-EORA database. Our findings show that undervaluation has a positive impact on forward GVC participation as well as backward GVC participation. While the former finding is intuitive, the latter may initially appear contradictory to prior research. Nonetheless, this result is consistent with the underlying concept that domestic and foreign value-added within GVCs are complementary in the production process. Hence, producing and exporting more domestic value added increases the derived demand for imported foreign value added.

Therefore, in our view, the interplay between domestic and foreign value added would explain the positive impact of undervaluation on backward GVC participation. Moreover, accounting for the quality of institutions and the degree of digitalisation, we demonstrate that undervaluation can serve as a catalyst for GVCs in countries with deficient institutions.

We also find that the positive impact of undervaluation is further magnified for countries with higher levels of digitalisation. Finally, we consistently observe a positive impact of undervaluation, irrespective of a country’s position within the value chain (either upstream or downstream).

Implications for policy

A number of policy recommendations stem from our research. First, undervaluation can act as a second-best solution to mitigate the economic cost of poor institutions and market failures that penalise the tradable sector and value-added exports.

A first-best policy would consist of identifying specific market failures and implementing tailored solutions. But in the presence of a manufacturing sector that has existing or potential capacity to export, undervaluation can be perceived as a short-term stepping-stone before a comprehensive industrial policy can be launched.

Many aspects of an economy, including the level of financial development, the quality of institutions and the degree of digitalisation, matter for the impact of undervaluation on GVC participation. Hence, to maintain the positive effect of RER undervaluation, exchange rate policy should be coupled with other policies.

Nonetheless, while this policy is doable in the short term, it is not sustainable in the long run. Deeper reforms to improve institutions and attain a higher level of digital transformation are needed.

Further reading

Abdou, M, I El Badawi, P Plane and C Zaki (2024) ‘Unravelling the Nexus Between Exchange Rate Undervaluation and Global Value Chains Participation’, ERF Working Paper No. 1709.

Elbadawi, I, and C Zaki (2021) ‘Exchange Rate Undervaluation, Economic Institutions and Exports Performance: Evidence from Firm-level Data’, International Journal of Trade and Global Markets 14(1): 62-93.

Nouira, R, P Plane and K Sekkat (2011) ‘Exchange Rate Undervaluation and Manufactured Exports: A Deliberate Strategy?’, Journal of Comparative Economics 39(4): 584-601.

Rodrik, D (1986) ‘Disequilibrium Exchange Rates as Industrialization Policy’, Journal of Development Economics 23(1): 89-106.

Tan, KG, LN Trieu Duong and HY Chuah (2019) ‘Impact of Exchange Rates on ASEAN’s Trade in the Era of Global Value Chains: An Empirical Assessment’, Journal of International Trade and Economic Development 28(7): 873-901.

Most read

Egypt’s labour market: new survey data for evidence-based decision-making

As Egypt faces substantial social and economic shifts, understanding the labour market is crucial for designing policies that promote employment and inclusive economic growth. This column introduces the latest wave of the Egypt Labor Market Panel Survey, which provides fresh, nationally representative data that are vital for examining these dynamics.

The evolution of labour supply in Egypt

Egypt stands at a critical point in its demographic and labour market evolution. As this column explains, while fertility rates have dropped, reducing long-term demographic pressures, the ‘echo generation’, children of the youth bulge, will soon enter the labour market, intensifying the need for policies to accelerate job creation. At the same time, participation in the labour force, particularly among women and young people, is declining, partly as a result of discouragement.

More jobs, better jobs and inclusive jobs: the promise of renewable energy

Among the many economic and environmental challenges facing the countries of the Middle East and North Africa (MENA), two stand out: the need for jobs and the need to combat the threat of climate change by moving away from reliance on fossil fuels. As this column explains, embracing renewable energy technologies presents an opportunity for the region to diversify its economy, mitigate the possible negative impacts of digital technologies on existing jobs, reduce its carbon footprint and create significant levels of employment, particularly for women and the youth, across a variety of sectors.

Sanctions and energy efficiency in Iran’s industries

What is the effect of economic sanctions on the energy efficiency of Iran’s industries? This column reports the findings of new research, which examines the impact of sanction intensity within industrial sub-sectors of the Iranian economy on their energy efficiency.

Towards a productive, inclusive and green economy in MENA

Decarbonisation of the global economy is a huge opportunity for countries in the Middle East and North Africa. As this column explains, they can supercharge their development by breaking into fast-growing industries that will help the world to reduce its emissions and reach net zero, as well as offering greater employment opportunities and new export lines. Micro, small and medium enterprises in the region can lead the transition to a cleaner and sustainable future, but this may require the formation of clusters of firms that overcome some of the constraints that their limited size could involve.

Poverty and plutonomy: measuring extreme bipolarisation in the Arab world

Inequality in the Arab world is not just a question of extreme poverty or extreme affluence: it’s about both. This column presents research that uses the lenses of both poverty analysis and plutonomy analysis to capture the extreme polarisation between the poor, who suffer from exclusion and deprivation, and the ultra-wealthy, who wield immense power over economic and political systems.

Participation of Arab countries in global value chains

To what extent are countries in the Arab region participating in the global value chains (GVCs) that now dominate world trade? What are the main determinants of engagement in GVCs? And what are the expected benefits for Arab countries from joining them? This column answers these questions, concluding that it is important to focus on the products in which countries both enjoy a natural comparative advantage and can increase domestic value added in the intermediate and final parts of the production process.

Growth in the Middle East and North Africa

What is the economic outlook for the Middle East and North Africa? How is the current conflict centred in Gaza affecting economies in the region? What are the potential long-term effects of conflict on development? And which strategies can MENA countries adopt to accelerate economic growth? This column outlines the findings in the World Bank’s latest half-yearly MENA Economic Update, which answers these questions and more.

The future of regionalism in the Arab world: a political economy view

The potential growth benefits of greater trade integration of the Arab countries, both within the Middle East and with the rest of the world economy, have long been discussed. But as this column explains, in the current climate of international political and economic relations, moves towards trade liberalisation and new or deeper trade agreements are unlikely to happen. Policy-makers in the region need to pursue alternative strategies to develop their economies.

Climate change: a growing threat to sustainable development in Tunisia

Tunisia’s vulnerability to extreme weather events is intensifying, placing immense pressure on vital sectors such as agriculture, energy and water resources, exacerbating inequalities and hindering social progress. This column explores the economic impacts of climate change on the country, its implications for achieving the sustainable development goals, and the urgent need for adaptive strategies and policy interventions.