Economic Research Forum (ERF)

Bottom incomes and the measurement of poverty and inequality

867
With negative and zero incomes being widely reported in household surveys, it is essential to understanding who is reporting them in order to generate a consistent ordering among households, and measure poverty and inequality accurately. This column summaries evidence from an investigation of the prevalence and consequences of non-positive incomes using 57 harmonised surveys covering 12 Mediterranean countries over the period 1995-2016.

In a nutshell

Understanding the bottom tail of an income distribution is important since it includes the income and wealth poor, the groups most in need of assistance and the primary target of social protection policies.

The poverty identification and inequality measurement problems posed by negative and especially zero incomes reported in household surveys are not trivial: they deserve attention and careful modelling by academics and practitioners.

Since uprisings in MENA have been linked to poverty and unequal economic opportunities, a better understanding of the scale of these problems can give policy-makers the tools to reduce social discontent and even fix some obstacles to growth.

Incomes in surveys suffer from various measurement problems, most notably in the lower and upper tails. This is known to bias the measurement of inequality, an issue that has generated a significant body of research covering high and low-income countries alike.

Statistical agencies and researchers working on poverty or inequality tend to ‘bottom-code’ or censor incomes at some low values such as zero, but this approach produces its own statistical problems. Some scholars have acknowledged the shortcomings with uncorrected statistics or those based on naïve corrections, and have studied the sensitivity of inequality indices to changes in bottom values. Some have proposed the use of parametric modelling similar to what has become accepted for top incomes.

Understanding the bottom tail of an income distribution is important from a policy perspective, arguably even more important than understanding the top tail of the distribution. The bottom tail includes the income and wealth poor, the groups most in need of assistance and the primary target of social protection policies.

Miscounting the poor affects the measurement of poverty and inequality, and contributes to bias in targeting exercises such as proxy means testing. This results in larger inclusion and exclusion errors, which have direct negative consequences for the livelihoods of the poor and vulnerable.

The presence of negative incomes may contribute to mismeasuring households’ wellbeing, as well as poverty and inequality.  Evidence from comparing the distribution of self-employment income in survey and tax data in Latin America suggests that this income tends to be under-reported in surveys across all distribution quantiles.

Both tax evasion and poor recall can be at play. Hence, negative incomes may come from under-reporting of self-employment or capital incomes, implying that some of the households reporting negative incomes may be non-poor or even wealthy households.

Even when negative or zero incomes are accurate, including them in the distribution of incomes can be problematic for the purpose of distributional analysis, because these values may not reflect the households’ short-term or long-term capabilities, consumption or welfare.

Households’ overconsumption is a case in point. Accruing debt may be a survival strategy for the poor, an investment strategy for the middle class or a tax evasion strategy for the rich.

We may expect small negative incomes to be prevalent among chronically poor people who are temporarily in trouble, and large negative values among chronically rich people under-reporting, or writing off capital losses from past years. Large tax adjustments and social contribution withholdings may not reflect what was due on current income. Private transfers may not mean net outflows of resources or welfare.

These are not theoretical squabbles as negative incomes are quite prevalent in household surveys. For example, in the sample of 354 household surveys in the Luxembourg Income Study (LIS) database, 229 surveys contain negative disposable household incomes. In 12 surveys, negative incomes account for over 1% of non-zero incomes, and number up to 584 observations in a national survey.

Moreover, these negative incomes are not trivial in size. Mean negative income is as large in absolute value as 754% of mean nationwide positive income, and exceeds 200% of mean nationwide income in 15 surveys.

Zero incomes are also prevalent in household surveys. Among the 354 LIS surveys, 270 surveys contain zero incomes. In 22 surveys, zero incomes account for over 1% of non-negative incomes, and number up to 1,213 households. The inclusion of these incomes in poverty and inequality measures presents its own challenges.

In sum, understanding who is who between negative and zero incomes is essential for generating a consistent ordering among households, and measuring poverty and inequality correctly.

In our new study (Hlasny et al, 2020), we investigate the prevalence and consequences of non-positive incomes using 57 harmonised surveys covering 12 Mediterranean countries over the period 1995-2016. We find that the main source of negative disposable incomes in three-quarters of all surveys is negative self-employment income. High tax and social security withholdings and high self-paid social security contributions also account for negative incomes in some countries.

Interestingly, when surveys are sorted by the frequency of negative disposable household incomes, negative self-employment income shows up as the top source of their prevalence. When surveys are sorted by the relative magnitude of negative incomes, high inter-household transfers and undue social security and other burdens dominate as sources of the high relative magnitude of negative incomes.

The prevalence of negative incomes is thus primarily due to negative self-employment incomes, while the extreme values of negative incomes are typically due to extremely high social security contributions, non-income taxes and paid remittances.

We also find that households with negative incomes are typically as well off as (or even better off than) other households in terms of material wellbeing (see Figure 1). They appear to be healthier and as highly educated. By contrast, zero-income households are materially deprived, even though their human capital (it terms of health and educational attainment) is not clearly lower than that of their compatriots.

Adjusting poverty and inequality measures for these issues can alter these measures significantly. Applying standard statistical adjustments for negative and zero incomes – data trimming or bottom-coding – we obtain corrections of up to 2.3 percentage points of the Gini coefficient, and 1.5 points of the poverty headcount ratio.

But even these approaches have limitations. They do not use all information available in surveys, they do not replace unreliable zero or negative incomes with more realistic values, and they may produce truncated income distributions with discontinuous point-mass at zero.

One alternative approach proposed in previous research to address the question of truncation has been modelling non-positive incomes using a smooth parametric distribution function such as the Pareto function (Van Kerm, 2007). We test this approach but find that Pareto distributions do not fit the observed negative incomes well, sometimes predicting unrealistically large income dispersion among negatives.

A further alternative is to replace non-positive incomes using the best-matching positives by means of classic matching methods or machine learning algorithms. We test this approach using a random forest classifier based on households’ characteristics and find it to be more viable than the previous methods as a correction approach.

It produces a continuous distribution of overall incomes without a point-density at zero, and converts non-positive incomes into realistic positive values based on households’ observed characteristics. This imputation shows sensible results across multiple countries and across several model specifications that we try. It also lowers the estimated Gini by up to 1.7 points, and the estimated poverty headcount ratio (incidentally) also by up to 1.7 points.

These preliminary estimations, conducted under rather conservative assumptions and modelling specifications, suggest that the poverty identification and inequality measurement problems posed by negative and especially zero incomes are not trivial, and deserve attention and careful modelling by academics and practitioners.

In relation to the ‘static’ problem of non-positive incomes, our corrections produce more accurate inequality and poverty indexes for the majority of countries. But in relation to the ‘dynamic’ problem of non-positive incomes for measuring the evolution of inequality and poverty over time, we find only limited evidence that our corrections reduce the volatility of inequality and poverty indexes across survey waves, as would be desired from correction methods.

Where do we go from here? Moving beyond truncation or Pareto estimations and adopting more modern techniques such as matching and machine learning classifiers, should allow us to model negative as well as zero incomes more sensibly. Imputation using random forest classification shows some promise in this respect.

More importantly, extending the analysis to a greater range of bottom incomes – say the extreme 5-10% as research on top incomes has been doing, or all incomes falling short of households’ consumption – promises to yield more determinate corrections. We should find more clearly that the corrections provide a dynamic benefit in the form of reduced volatility of inequality and poverty indexes over time. With the corrected bottom incomes, we should be able to re-evaluate their impact on multidimensional deprivation and poverty.

The policy implications of this research in progress are clear. Our results are relevant for fiscal redistribution, aid targeting and – in the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) – the use of revenues from natural resources. Since uprisings in the MENA region have been linked to the problems of poverty and unequal economic opportunities, a better understanding of the scale of these problems can give policy-makers the tools to bring social discontent down, and even fix some traps and obstacles to economic growth.

Figure 1: Socio-economic characteristics of households with non-positive disposable income

Source: Authors’ calculations based on LIS-ERF database surveys.

 

Further reading

Hlasny, Vladimir, Lidia Ceriani and Paolo Verme (2020) ‘Bottom incomes and the measurement of poverty and inequality’, ERF Working Paper No. 1393.

Van Kerm, Philippe (2007) ‘Extreme incomes and the estimation of poverty and inequality indicators from EU-SILC’, Working Paper 2007-01, CEPS-Instead IRISS.

Most read

EU climate policy: potential effects on the exports of Arab countries

The carbon border adjustment mechanism aims to ensure that Europe’s green objectives are not undermined by the relocation of production to parts of the world with less ambitious climate policies – but it could impose substantial costs on developing countries that export to the European Union. This column examines the potential impact on exporters in the Arab world – and outlines possible policy responses that could mitigate the economic damage.

Financial development, corruption and informality in MENA

Reducing the extent of informality in the Middle East and North Africa would help to promote economic growth. This column reports evidence on how corruption and financial development influence the size of the informal economy in countries across the region. The efficiency of the financial sector in MENA economies reduces the corruption incentive for firms to seek to join and stay in the formal sector.

Green hydrogen production and exports: could MENA countries lead the way?

The Arab region stands at the threshold of a transformative opportunity to become a global leader in green hydrogen production and exports. But as this column explains, achieving this potential will require substantial investments, robust policy frameworks and a commitment to technological innovation.

Climate change threats and how the Arab countries should respond

The Arab region is highly vulnerable to extreme events caused by climate change. This column outlines the threats and explores what can be done to ward off disaster, not least moving away from the extraction of fossil fuels and taking advantage of the opportunities in renewable energy generation. This would both mitigate the potential for further environmental damage and act as a catalyst for more and better jobs, higher incomes and improved social outcomes.

Freedom: the missing piece in analysis of multidimensional wellbeing

Political philosophy has long emphasised the importance of freedom in shaping a meaningful life, yet it is consistently overlooked in assessments of human wellbeing across multiple dimensions. This column focuses on the freedom to express opinions, noting that it is shaped by both formal laws and informal social dynamics, fluctuating with the changing cultural context, particularly in the age of social media. Data on public opinion in Arab countries over the past decade are revealing about how this key freedom is perceived.

Child stunting in Tunisia: an alarming rise

Child stunting in Tunisia seemed to have fallen significantly over the past two decades. But as this column reports, new analysis indicates that the positive trend has now gone dramatically into reverse. Indeed, the evidence is unequivocal: the nutritional health of the country’s youngest citizens is rapidly deteriorating and requires immediate and decisive action.

Exchange rate undervaluation: the impact on participation in world trade

Can currency undervaluation influence participation in world trade through global value chains (GVC)? This column reports new evidence on the positive impact of an undervalued real exchange rate on the involvement of a country’s firms in GVCs. Undervaluation acts as an economy-wide industrial policy, supporting the competitiveness of national exports in foreign markets vis-à-vis those of other countries.

New horizons for economic transformation in the GCC countries

The countries of the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) have historically relied on hydrocarbons for economic growth. As this column explains ahead of a high-level ERF policy seminar in Dubai, emerging technologies like artificial intelligence, blockchain and robotics – what some call the fourth industrial revolution – present a unique opportunity for the region to reduce its dependence on oil and make the transition to a knowledge-based economy.

Shifting public trust in governments across the Arab world

The Arab Spring, which began over a decade ago, was driven by popular distrust in governments of the region. The column reports on how public trust has shifted since then, drawing on survey data collected soon after the uprising and ten years later. The findings reveal a dynamic and often fragile landscape of trust in Arab governments from the early 2010s to the early 2020s. Growing distrust across many countries should raise concerns about future political and social instability.

Corruption in Iran: the role of oil rents

How do fluctuations in oil rents influence levels of corruption in Iran? This column reports the findings of new research, which examines the impact of increases in the country’s oil revenues on corruption, including the mechanisms through which the effects occur – higher inflation, greater public spending on the military and the weakness of democratic institutions.




LinkedIn