Economic Research Forum (ERF)

Replace discretion with rules to boost economic performance

1162
A government that adopts institutional reform to increase policy credibility and enhance the degree of competition may be rewarded with improved economic performance. This column reports the experience of Turkey in the early 2000s, a period in which anti-corruption and economic reform programmes that promoted more rule-based policy-making made significant positive contributions to growth.

In a nutshell

Between 2002 and 2007, a period of major institutional reform, Turkey experienced one of the highest sustained growth rates in per capita income in the country’s history.

Recently, the government has weakened regulators’ independence and introduced new schemes with greater discretionary powers.

As a result, economic growth is less likely to be driven by open competition and will rely on discretionary instruments to generate investment.

Before the 2000s, economic policy-making in Turkey was based on discretion and patronage rather than rules. This put a significant amount of stress on public finances, resulting in macroeconomic instability.

In the wake of the 2000/01 financial crisis, the government made major institutional reforms that at least nominally reduced its discretion, delegated policy-making authority to independent bodies, and introduced more rule-based policy-making processes into key segments of the economy. Turkey’s candidacy for membership of the European Union (EU) provided an institutional anchor and guided these institutional reforms.

Contours of institutional change

Governments often use trade, investment or industrial policies to distribute rents towards favoured businesses. In the case of Turkey, these options had been limited since the mid-1990s because of a customs union with the EU and membership of the World Trade Organization.

Both of these, but especially the customs union, limited Turkey’s ability to implement selective support policies. Indeed, most of industrial policy instruments that Turkey has used in the last two decades have been ‘horizontal’ in nature, geared towards areas such as regional development and research and development. What these meant was that in tradable sectors, the scope for favouritism was limited.

There were a number of factors that were conducive to additional institutional reform in the 2000s. The first was the deep economic crisis of 2000/01. As is typically the case, the crisis increased the bargaining power of international organisations, such as the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank, as well as reform-minded people in the bureaucracy. This created an opportunity to implement major institutional reforms within a time span of one to two years.

The reforms included establishing independent regulatory authorities in banking, telecommunications, energy and public procurement. In a major step, the central bank was given independence. Transparency and control of the public budget was significantly increased and the ability of the government to use off-budget expenditures (for example, through government-owned banks) was significantly reduced.

The second important factor was the EU. While the customs union was already in place, Turkey became a candidate country in 1999. EU regulations provided templates for institutional reforms in many areas and most of the laws enacted in the period from 1999 to 2002 were inspired by EU legislation. Importantly, competition law had already been enacted in 1994 as a condition of the customs union.

The third crucial factor was the coming to power of the Justice and Development Party (AKP) in 2002. AKP was elected on a platform of anti-corruption and political and economic reform. At that time, it had a very strong pro-EU attitude, which reflected a significant shift away from the discourse of the traditional political Islam movement out of which it grew. The AKP embraced most (though not all) reforms. Being a conservative party, they were careful about fiscal policy and did not allow demands for wealth redistribution to result in the deterioration of the budget.

Politics trumps economic institutions

It is difficult to measure the impact of all these institutional changes on economic performance. Nevertheless, it is notable that between 2002 and 2007, Turkey experienced one of the highest sustained growth rates in per capita income in the country’s history. Macroeconomic stability was achieved relatively quickly and inflation was reduced to single digits, a substantial achievement given past experiences of inflation. The reforms created an environment more conducive to reap the benefits of competition and creative destruction.

But in the last few years, the political environment in Turkey has started to change radically. For various reasons, the prospect of EU membership has weakened and lost its allure. The government has turned increasingly authoritarian and intolerant of dissent. The high degree of cooperation between the AKP and the Gulen movement (a tight conservative network organised within business as well as the police and the judiciary) was replaced by open hostility when police apparently associated with the movement instigated corruption investigations against AKP ministers.

Change in the political environment took its toll on institutions of economic policy. Independence of the regulatory authorities and the central bank became increasingly challenged. In 2011, the government passed a law stating that regulatory agencies would be ‘inspected’ by the associated ministries, in effect giving the government an instrument that can be used to harass regulatory agencies.

More generally, state authority started to be used against businesses that fell out of favour with the government (or the president) or that were regarded as part of the Gulen network. The central bank came under intense pressure to keep interest rates low.

With regard to investment incentives, the government has introduced new schemes that give it more discretionary power. It appears that the more the government moves away from rule-based policy-making and resorts to discretion, the less it will be able to rely on the competitive process to generate growth, further increasing its incentives to rely on discretionary instruments to generate investment.

Once created, formal measures of independence will protect rule-based policy-making from political encroachment, but not indefinitely. Ultimately, it is the nature of political institutions that determine the nature of economic institutions.

In the golden years of the early 2000s in Turkey, the evolution of economic institutions largely reflected a political orientation that apparently was interested in EU accession. Currently, the evolution seems to be closely influenced by the more authoritarian and survival instincts of the government.

Further reading

Atiyas, Izak (2016) ‘Replace Discretion with Rules: How Policy Reform Can Boost Economic Performance’, ERF Policy Brief No. 10.

Most read

A Macroeconomic Accounting of Unemployment in Jordan:  Unemployment is mainly an issue for adults and men

Since unemployment rates in Jordan are higher among young people and women than other groups, unemployment is commonly characterised as a youth and gender issue. However, the majority of the country’s unemployed are adults and men. This suggests that unemployment is primarily a macroeconomic issue challenge for the entire labour market. The appropriate response therefore is coordinated fiscal, monetary, structural and institutional policies, while more targeted measures can still benefit specific groups.

Tunisia’s energy transition: the key role of small businesses

Micro, small and medium-sized enterprises (MSMEs) play a critical role in Tunisia’s economy, contributing significantly to GDP and employment. As this column explains, they are also essential for advancing the country’s ambitions to make a successful transition from reliance on fossil fuels to more widespread use of renewable energy sources. A fair distribution of the transition’s benefits across all regions and communities will secure a future where MSMEs thrive as leaders in a prosperous, inclusive and sustainable Tunisia.

The hidden potential of Jordan’s small firms for driving a green transition

For Jordan, a green transition represents an enormous transformative opportunity. But a decade-long increase in the use of renewable energy has not freed the country of its economic woes. This column explores the currently underused yet potentially powerful force of micro, small and medium-sized enterprises – and proposes policies that could improve the investment climate and clear legislative and regulatory barriers.

Global value chains and sustainable development

What is the role of exchange rate undervaluation in promoting participation in global value chains by firms in developing countries? What is the impact of the stringency of national environmental regulations on firms’ GVC participation? And how do firms’ political connections affect their participation in GVCs? These questions will be explored for the MENA region at a special session of the ERF annual conference, which takes place in Cairo in April 2025.

Adoption of decentralised solar energy: lessons from Palestinian households

The experience of Palestinian households offers a compelling case study of behavioural adaptation to energy poverty via solar water heater adoption. This column highlights the key barriers to solar energy adoption in terms of both the socio-economic status and dwellings of potential users. Policy-makers need to address these barriers to ensure a just and equitable transition, particularly for households in conflict-affected areas across the MENA region.