Economic Research Forum (ERF)

Contours of Middle East economics

1060
A new handbook on the Middle East economy has just been published. As the volume’s editor explains in this column, knowledge of Middle Eastern economies as an autonomous field within economics is of relatively recent origins and has evolved in uneven ways.

In a nutshell

The ‘resource curse’ theory, originating in the 1970s, is arguably one of the more significant and lasting contributions of the region to development theory and one that originated there and travelled outwards.

One legacy of the Arab Spring was to lead to greater and more explicit recognition of the importance of political and social factors among economists.

Just as sophisticated financial models did not rescue the world from the global financial crisis, in the Middle East too, the challenge is not to lose our focus on the complex but real problems of the region.

Sir William Arthur Lewis (1915-91) is widely recognised as a towering figure and a forerunner in development economics. He was the first development economist to be awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics (jointly in 1979), and his seminal paper ‘Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour’, published in 1954, has adorned reading lists and textbooks for generations of students.

What is less well known is that in 1938, he was the first black lecturer to be appointed at the London School of Economics (LSE) and later the first ever black professor in the UK. Even more significantly, his ground-breaking appointment came with restrictions, which reflected the racial prejudices of the time (he was from the Caribbean island of St Lucia): it had to be approved by the LSE’s Court of Governors; his total teaching hours were limited; and he was only permitted to teach groups of students, which barred him from holding individual tutorials (Forbes-Taylor and Walker, 2020).

Perhaps even more obscure is the knowledge that our region – the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) – had some linkage to his seminal paper. In the spring of 1953, Lewis visited Egypt, where he delivered three lectures on industrialisation (Lewis, 1953).

According to him, the initial idea behind his two-sector model of economic development came to him in 1952 when he was ‘walking down the road in Bangkok’. But this has not deterred some to suggest that ‘in many ways, the Egyptian lectures previewed the main ideas in Lewis’s 1954 article’ (Tignor, 2006). After all, Lewis had listed Egypt along with India and Jamaica in his paper, where the ‘unlimited supply of labour’ was ‘obviously the relevant assumption’ (Lewis, 1954).

This fascinating story might be a good starting point for sketching out the contours of Middle East economics. But to seek the genesis of the field in Lewis’s work or even in this era is a long shot.

On the contrary, in my introduction to a recently published edited volume, The Routledge Handbook on the Middle East Economy, which features contributions from more than 15 ERF research fellows, I remark that: ‘Knowledge of Middle Eastern economies as an autonomous field within economics is of relatively recent origins and has evolved in uneven ways’ (Hakimian, 2021).

The handbook – to date, the first one on our region’s economy – consists of 22 chapters covering a broad range of pertinent topics. It shows that despite its relative novelty, Middle East economics has come a long way over the last fifty years, morphing into a specialist field within applied development economics, the political economy of development, area studies and development studies.

Writing the introduction enabled me to reflect on two inter-related intellectual curiosities: to examine the influence of socio-economic and political contexts on knowledge construction in economics (both theoretical and applied); and to examine if the region has been merely a playground to external ideas or whether it has also contributed to the growth and maturity of economic development theories and policies.

After a cursory look at the early period in the 1950s and 1960s, which was marked by a number of limited, albeit seminal, works, I focus on the bumpy journey along which Middle East economics has travelled over three distinct periods: first, the oil boom of the 1970s; next, the growth crisis of the 1980s and 1990s; and more recently, the tumultuous period before and after 2010, which saw unprecedented social and political upheavals marking the Arab uprisings.

There was, for instance, a sharp contrast between the 1970s – the ‘golden’ oil boom era – when the region’s economic fortunes were transformed and the 1980s and 1990s when they were reversed. With the meteoric rise in the importance of MENA on the world energy and financial scenes came also one of the earliest and most notable contributions to the political economy of oil and development in MENA.

Despite the initial anonymity of Hossein Mahdavy’s pioneering 1970 study of the ‘rentier states’, over time it led to a copious body of research evidence, which correlated oil rents with poor economic outcomes in resource-rich economies. The ensuing ‘resource curse’ theory, arguably is one of the more significant and lasting contributions of the region to development theory and one which originated there and travelled outwards.

This was in sharp contrast with the 1980s and 1990s, which were marked by widespread growth and employment crises across the region. The spotlight now shifted to explaining the seemingly inferior comparative performance of MENA. This carved up an important space for the international financial institutions (IFIs), which pushed for reform under the auspices of various structural adjustment programmes, especially in the region’s ailing economies – Morocco, Tunisia, Jordan and Egypt.

Middle East economics was now in full swing, enjoying both quantitative growth and qualitative transformation. On one hand, there was a notable rise in intellectual output and publications and the expansion of research capacity in the region (Pfeifer, 2016); and on the other, the subject broadened to encompass ‘structural economic imbalances … deficient political systems, conditions of war and conflict and even culture and religion’ (Yousef, 2004).

Perhaps the biggest challenge to the profession came from outside the field around 2010. The Arab uprisings at this time took most analysts by surprise and economists were no exception. This is partly because the relatively better performance in the decade before had led to optimism. Some IFIs even felt justified to take credit for the apparent dividends of the policies they had advocated. The events, however, exposed the limitations of too narrow a focus on select ‘fundamental’ macro indicators and the risks associated with missing the bigger social and political pictures.

The World Bank’s subsequent mea culpa, confirmed that not all had gone according to plan (World Bank, 2015). In a short opinion piece on ‘Why economists failed to antici­pate the Arab Spring’, I questioned the value of economic determinism as a basis for understanding revolutions and political upheaval (Hakimian, 2017).

The Arab Spring was followed by a period of soul searching, which helped to stretch the boundaries of the discipline. We thus witnessed not only greater quantitative growth of research papers and projects, but also a lateral expansion in the scope and range of topics covered. Even ERF – the largest professional network of MENA economists – noticeably engaged more directly with social and political themes in its annual conferences after the Arab Spring.

This has undoubtedly enriched the scope and diversity of topics that have emerged including poverty and inequality, human development, the role of religion and Islam in development, crony capitalism, institutions, governance and transition to democracy, gender, impacts of conflict and forced displacements (refugees), to mention some. These themes feature in the handbook including a significant number of contributions from the ERF community, as mentioned above.

Today, though much enriched and established, Middle East economics sits uncomfortably between two disciplines: area studies on one hand and mainstream economics on the other. In some ways, however, this contextual position also demarcates some of the main challenges our field faces today.

As with area studies, it has to avoid the pitfalls of exceptionalism especially after the disappointments that have followed the demise of the Arab Spring. Within economics too, it has to avoid the limitations of over-reliance on mathematical finesse and elaborate model-building. Just as the sophisticated financial models did not rescue the world from the global financial crisis of 2007-09, in the Middle East too, the challenge is not to lose our focus on the complex but real problems of the region.

As Dani Rodrik once observed, ‘we use math [in economics] not because we are smart, but because we are not smart enough’ (Rodrik, 2007; emphasis in original). Happily, the region can boast a lot of talent and economics is no exception to this.

 

Further reading

Forbes-Taylor, Shay, and Brian Walker (2020) ‘The Legacy of Sir Arthur Lewis’ (video).

Hakimian, Hassan (2017) ‘Why Economists Missed the Arab Spring,’ Project Syndicate, 20 March.

Hakimian, Hassan (2021) The Routledge Handbook on the Middle East Economy, Routledge.

Lewis, W Arthur (1953) ‘Aspects of Industrialization: National Bank of Egypt’, Fiftieth Anniversary Commemoration Lecture, Cairo.

Lewis, W Arthur (1954) ‘Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour’, Manchester School 22(2): 139-91.

Mahdavy, Hossein (1970) ‘The Patterns and Problems of Economic Development in Rentier States: The Case of Iran’, in Cook, MA, ed. (1970), Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East, Oxford University Press.

Pfeifer, Karen (2016) ‘Oil on the Waters? Middle East Studies and Economics of the Middle East’, in Seteny Shami and Cynthia Miller-Idriss, eds (2016) Middle East Studies for the New Millennium, Infrastructures of Knowledge, Social Science Research Council and New York University Press.

Rodrik, Dani (2007) ‘Why We Use Math in Economics’, weblog, 4 September.

Tignor, Robert L (2006) ‘Unlimited Supplies of Labor’, in Tignor, Robert L (2006) W. Arthur Lewis and the Birth of Development Economics, Princeton University Press.

World Bank (2015) ‘Inequality, Uprisings, and Conflict in the Arab World’, MENA Economic Monitor, October.

Yousef, Tarik M (2004) ‘Development, Growth and Policy Reform in the Middle East and North Africa since 1950’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(3): 91-116.

Most read

Making trade agreements more environmentally friendly in the MENA region

Trade policy can play a significant role in efforts to decarbonise the global economy. But as this column explains, there need to be more environmental provisions in trade agreements in which developing countries participate – and stronger legal enforcement of those provisions at the international level. The MENA region would benefit substantially from such changes.

Jordan: navigating through multiple crises

Jordan’s real GDP per capita is today no higher than it was 40 years ago. While external factors have undoubtedly had an adverse effect on the country’s economic outcomes, weak macroeconomic management and low public spending on investment and the social sectors have also played a substantial role. This column explores what can be done to reduce high public debt, accelerate private sector development and enhance social outcomes.

Iran’s globalisation and Saudi Arabia’s defence budget

How might Saudi Arabia react to Iran's renewed participation in global trade and investment? This column explores whether the expanding economic globalisation of Iran, following the lifting of nuclear sanctions, could yield a peace dividend for Saudi Arabia, consequently dampening the Middle East arms competition. These issues have attracted increased attention in recent times, notably after a pivotal agreement between the two countries in March 2023, marking the resumption of their political ties after a seven-year conflict.

Egypt and Iraq: amenities, environmental quality and taste for revolution

The Middle East and North Africa is a region marked by significant political turbulence. This column explores a novel dimension of these upheavals: the relationship between people’s satisfaction with, on one hand, the amenities to which they have access and the environmental quality they experience, and, on the other hand, their inclination towards revolutionary actions. The data come from the World Value Survey collected in 2018 in Egypt and Iraq.

Global value chains and domestic innovation: evidence from MENA firms

Global interlinkages play a significant role in enhancing innovation by firms in developing countries. In particular, as this column explains, participation in global value chains fosters a variety of innovation activities. Since some countries in the Middle East and North Africa display a downward trend on measures of global innovation, facilitating the GVC participation of firms in the region is a prospective channel for stimulating underperforming innovation.

Labour market effects of robots: evidence from Turkey

Evidence from developed countries on the impact of automation on labour markets suggests that there can be negative effects on manufacturing jobs, but also mechanisms for workers to move into the services sector. But this narrative may not apply in developing economies. This column reports new evidence from Turkey on the effects of robots on labour displacement and job reallocation.

Food insecurity in Tunisia during and after the Covid-19 pandemic

Labour market instability, rising unemployment rates and soaring food prices due to Covid-19 are among the reasons for severe food insecurity across the world. This grim picture is evident in Tunisia, where the government continues to provide financial and food aid to vulnerable households after the pandemic. But as this column explains, the inadequacy of some public policies is another important factors causing food insecurity.

Manufacturing firms in Egypt: trade participation and outcomes for workers

International trade can play a large and positive role in boosting economic growth, reducing poverty and making progress towards gender equality. These effects result in part from the extent to which trade is associated with favourable labour market outcomes. This column presents evidence of the effects of Egyptian manufacturing firms’ participation in exporting and importing on their workers’ productivity and average wages, and on women’s employment share.

Do capital inflows cause industrialisation or de-industrialisation?

There is a clear appeal for emerging and developing economies, including those in MENA, to finance investment in manufacturing industry at home with capital inflows from overseas. But as the evidence reported in this column indicates, this is a potentially risky strategy: rather than promoting industrialisation, capital flows can actually lead to lower manufacturing value added and/or a reallocation of resources towards industries with lower technology intensity.

Sustaining entrepreneurship: lessons from Iran

Does entrepreneurial activity naturally return to long-term average levels after big economic disturbances? This column presents new evidence from Iran on trends in entrepreneurship among various categories of firm size, sector and location – and suggests policies that could be effective in promoting entrepreneurial activities.